Wait a second!
More handpicked essays just for you.
More handpicked essays just for you.
capitalism in industrial revolution
roles of government
rise of capitalism during the industrial revolution
Don’t take our word for it - see why 10 million students trust us with their essay needs.
Recommended: capitalism in industrial revolution
What should be the state's role in the development process? Why has there been a neoliberal backlash against government involvement in development?
In theory, the role of the state in development should be a small one. Instead of following outmoded socialist central planning policies akin to those of the Eastern bloc in the twentieth century, poor countries should emulate the West and open up its markets to international trade; encourage the development of a vibrant and dynamic private sector; ensure that government spending is kept to a minimum; privatise all manner of inefficient and wasteful state-owned industries and overall, let the free market do its job. At least, that is the theory.
But it may not be that simple. Many historians correctly point out that the West was hardly the epitome of the free market and small government back in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries when it was first industrialising.[1] If anything, government intervention was the norm for quite a long time. The state played a role in shielding domestic manufacturers from the corrosive effects of trade, which (in their eyes) kick-started the Industrial Revolution in Great Britain; channelling capital to budding industrialists to invent and improve upon new and existing technologies; funding long-range expeditions to faraway lands like India and China to open up trade links, which, in absence of a guaranteed profit, would have turned away private investors; and finally, regulating and standardising all manner of industry as to ensure efficient and organised operation.
However, it takes negligible intellectual effort to simply use the post hoc ergo propter hoc logical fallacy and cherry pick evidence to suit one's world view. The same line of reasoning was used by racists in the 1800s to argue that Western Europe developed because it was made up of whites and Africa stagnated because it was made up of blacks. Such a position is, of course, absolutely ludicrous, and yet the same thought process is used by many who would argue that the state was the main reason that poor countries are now rich. It is one thing to say that the state intervened during the development phase of these countries, but it is quite another to say that its intervention caused such development.
Therefore, historians must pinpoint a single trend within the developed economies that led to the initial...
... middle of paper ...
...t to the World Bank and IMF for loans, who would only cooperate if these countries implemented painful (but arguably necessary) structural adjustment programs, which were designed to reorganise their economies along more market capitalist lines. Whereas in the fifties and sixties, developing countries were able to exploit the tensions between the US and USSR in order to garner all the financial support they required (Egypt's Nasser was particularly shrewd in this regard[5]), once the Cold War had wound down in the eighties and the Soviets had little money left to 'lend', the only option available was to borrow from the West.
LIST OF REFERENCES
Bernstein, WJ, The birth of plenty: How the prosperity of the modern world was created, McGraw-Hill, New York, 2004.
Chang, H, 'The market, the state and the institutions in economic development' in H Chang (ed.), Rethinking development economics, Anthem Press, London, 2003, pp. 41-60.
Heo, U, & T Roehrig, South Korea since 1980,CambridgeUniversity Press,Cambridge, 2010.
Knox, P, & Agnew, J, The geography of the world economy, 3rd edn, John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1998.
Kissinger, H, Diplomacy,Simon&Schuster,New York, 1994.
In an article entitled “Resisting and reshaping destructive development: social movements and globalizing networks”, P. Routledge describes neoliberal development, “Contemporary economic development is guided by the economic principles of neoliberalism and popularly termed ‘globalization’. The fundamental principal of this doctrine is ‘economic liberty’ for the powerful, that is that an economy must be free from the social and political ‘impediments,’ ‘fetters’, and ‘restrictions’ placed upon it by states trying to regulate in the name of the public interest. These ‘impediments’ - which include national economic regulations, social programs, and class compromises (i.e. national bargaining agreements between employers and trade unions, assuming these are allowed) - are considered barriers to the free flow of trade and capital, and the freedom of transnational corporations to exploit labor and the environment in their best interests. Hence, the doctrine argues that national economies should be deregulated (e.g. through the privatization of state enterprises) in order to promote the allocation of resources by “the market” which, in practice, means by the most powerful.” (Routledge)
Hojman, David. 1999. The Political Economy of Development and Democracy in the 1990’s. Pittsburgh, Pa.: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Goldfield, David. The Market Revolution and Social Reform. Vol. 1, chap. 12 in The American Journey, A History of the United States, by David R. Goldfield. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education, 2014.
Heilbroner, Robert. "The Economic Problem." The Making of the Economic Society. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1993. pp. 1-15
In States vs. Markets, Herman Schwartz presents two economic development strategies that have been employed by late industrial developers in order to either take advantage of existing comparative advantages or facilitate rapid industrial growth through state intervention and provision in order to gain a competitive foothold in world markets. Schwartz demonstrates how China was able to employ elements of these development strategies to generate capital from an abundant rural labour supply in order to pursue industrial development and attract foreign investment through economic reform starting in the late 1970's.
There is little doubt that the quarter century following post WWII reconstruction was a period of unprecedented prosperity and expansion for the world economy. For some twenty years after the conclusion of WWII, Keynesian economic policies in countries of the capitalist West were successful in generating rapid growth with high employment and accumulation. Global Capitalism had entered a period known as the Golden Age, where the United States played a dominant role in global stability and growth between 1950 and 1975. Unfortunately, all good thing must come to an end, as did the Golden Age in the late 1970’s when its collapse gave rise to neoliberalism.
The policies dictated by the IMF during the 80s and 90s, which were influential in destroying the economies of many developing countries, offer one example of the technocratic approach going awry. Today the realities of the developing world vary from country to country, but experts continue to be obsessed with setting goals and expecting that governments will reach them, without taking into account the likely impact on the local
This criticism has two main elements: that the external actors’ interests do not directly align with those of the weak state and that exogenous conceptions of the state fail to see value in sub-state indigenous governing bodies. External influence on the statebuilding process is not inherently bad. In fact, some states are so weak in capacity that monopoly of violence and provision of goods does not make it past the capital city. Without external forces and training, these states with low funds would be incapable of fulfilling their
Both arguments concerning the obstacles to development make valid points. The neoliberalism position focuses on the misguided policies enforced by the developing states. They argue that excessive government control of the domestic and the international economy of the state prevents economic growth, while fiscal discipline and non-intervention by the state’s governments allows the economy to stimulate. On the other hand, the dependency theory perspective, which focuses on the global order between rich and poor nations, argues that the wealthy states exploit the weak states, therefore, producing underdevelopment and global inequality.
...M. "INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MOBILITY IN HISTORY: PURCHASING-POWER PARITY ~ THE LONG RUN." National Bureau of Economic Research. Sept. 1996. Web. 15 Apr. 2014. .
The turn to neoliberalism began after the Second World War. The restructuring of state forms and of international relations was intended to prevent a return to conditions that occurred in the 1930s. It was supposed to avoid the recurrence of inter-state geopolitical rivalries that triggered the war. After both capitalism and communism failed, the only way to move forward was to create the right mixture of state, market, and democratic institutions to guarantee peace, inclusion, well-being, and stability according...
Reich, R. (1991). "The work of nations: Preparing ourselves for twenty-first century capitalism." New York: Alfred Knopf
“The process of globalization and the increasing role of non-state actors in global governance are undermining the role of the state as the principal actor in global policymaking.”
The neoclassical theory supports this as it was previously explained and suggested that the underdevelopment of some countries is due to the government’s poor state of intervention, encouraging corruption and inefficiency.
Community development uses methods that generate social inclusion, empowerment, power sharing, and collective action. Alan Twelvetress states community development work is “the process of assisting people to improve their own communities by undertaking autonomous collective action” (Twelvetress, 2008). In other words, it aims to reduce poverty and promote equality on both a local and national level.